CURTIN UNIVERSITY OF TECHNOLOGY
CURTIN BUSINESS SCHOOL
School of Economics and Finance
ECONOMICS (INTERNATIONAL) 311
ASSIGNMENT 1
Prepared For : Professor Harry Bloch
Prepared By : Chow Tai Wei, David
Student No. : 977438B
TABLE OF CONTENTS
1. INTRODUCTION *
2. THE HECKSCHER--OHLIN THEORY *
3. HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEOREM FOR AUSTRALIA'S PATTERN OF TRADE? *
4. Australia's pattern of international trade *
5. conclusion *
6. List of references *
7. Appendices *
The composition of Australia's exports has shifted dramatically away from the traditional dominance of rural products. According to Clark (1997), the four distinct changes of its export trade composition since World War II are:
Today, the largest shares of exports are still from the minerals and agricultural sectors. This is because Australia has a comparative advantage in these activities. The Heckscher-Ohlin theory can give us some insight into why this is so.
In this essay, we will define the Heckscher-Ohlin theory, and discuss its implications for the pattern of trade to be expected for Australia given her factor endowment. This will be compared with the current trade pattern to determine its goodness of fit. In addition, we will be highlighting whether Australia's trade is primarily inter-industry or intra-industry trade, and whether any other trade theories could help to better explain her trading pattern.
2. THE HECKSCHER--OHLIN THEORY
In the basic Ricardian model, comparative advantage could only be determined by differences in labour productivity between countries, as this classical economic model assumes that labour is the only factor of production. In the real world, however, differences in the countries' endowment of resources also play an important part in explaining the difference in relative commodity prices, thus comparative advantage between them.
One of the most influential theories in international economics, the Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) theory professes that international trade is largely driven by differences in countries' endowment of their resources, given a set of strict assumptions.
Consider a capital abundance country like Japan, and the land abundance Australia, both producing steel (capital intensive good) and wool (land intensive). If we illustrate the different relative factor endowments using the Edgeworth Box (in figure 1), we can see that the maximum amount of steel Japan can produce (at S4 ) exceeds the maximum amount Australia can produce (at S3) . Australia, having abundance of land, can produce more wool than Japan when both produce at maximum capacity (higher isoquant WA, 3 compared with WJ, 2).
Now representing this factor endowment differences using two PPFs, we have, at autarky, Japan consuming steel and wool at SJap and WJap respectively, while Australia consume at SAus and WAus (see figure 2). At these consumption mixes, both nations could achieve a level of common community indifference curve at CI0 (assuming both nations have identical demand structure.
Figure 1: Edgeworth Box diagram for differences in factor abundance
Credit: Figure 1 from Bloch (1998)
Figure 2: PPF diagrams for differences in factor abundance (in autarky)
Credit: Figure 2 from Bloch (1998)
Suppose now both countries open for trade (at international terms of trade), both countries could consume at CAustralia, Japan which lies outside their respective PPFs (see figure 3). In order to achieve this, Japan will have to export S0S1 of steel in exchange for W2W1 bales of imported wool from Australia, while Australia exports W0W1 bales of wools and imports S2S1 tonnes of steel from Japan. This consumption enables both nations to achieve a higher community indifference curve at CI1.
Figure 3: Trade when countries have identical tastes
Credit: Figure 1 from Bloch (1998)
Thus, we have shown that a capital abundance country like Japan would export capital intensive good like steel and import wool, while the land abundance Australia would export land intensive wool in exchange for imported steel. This is the major conclusion for the H-O theorem.
3. HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEOREM FOR AUSTRALIA'S PATTERN OF TRADE?
The Heckscher-Ohlin theorem states that a country will have a comparative advantage in those goods and services that are produced with factors of production which it has in relative abundance. Thus, a country will export the commodity that uses relatively intensively its relatively abundant factor of production, and import goods that uses relatively its relatively scarce factor of production.
To establish what Australia has in relative abundance is the first step in determining what it has a comparative advantage in. Casual observation by Lewis et al (1998, pg. 21) suggests, among other things, that it has a relative abundance of land, energy, mineral deposits, highly educated labour, natural beauty and fine weather. Thus, Australia can offer a comparative advantage in industries such as agriculture, mining, education services and tourism. It also suggests that Australia has a comparative disadvantage in basic manufacturing, as it is relatively scarce of low-skilled labour.
According to Promfret (1995), for the natural-resource-rich, lightly populated Australia, its key determinant of comparative advantage is its relative factor endowment with the rest of the world. This is because Australia is "very richly endowed with agricultural land and mineral and energy resources per worker" (ibid, pg. 30) coupled with a relatively highly skilled workforce. Promfret summarised these factors graphically with a Leamer triangle shown overleaf. Compared with other economies in examination, Australia appears high in the NWD space of the Leamer triangle, indicating that it is "very abundantly endowed with natural resources per worker and has well above average stocks of produced capital per worker, relative to the rest of the world" (ibid, pg. 32). This fits Lewis's observation, and would also expect Australia to be a net exporter of raw materials, food, fibre and processed primary products, and a net importer of basic manufactures and services.
N.A.
Figure 4: Relative endowments of natural resources, labour and produced capital, various economies, 1991
Source: Adapted from Leamer (1987) using data from the World Bank (1993).
It should be noted that comparative advantage could change over time in response to changes in its own or other economies' resources (Lewis et al 1998, Promfret 1995). For example, discovery of new fuel or mineral deposits in Australia, or a depletion of the natural resources elsewhere in the world would see Australia exporting more energy raw materials. On the same note, there is a scope for Australia to develop new industries or manufacturing processes to replace the declining industries such as textiles, clothing and footwear.
4. Australia's pattern of international trade
As mentioned in the introduction, Australia's export has shifted away from its historical dominance in primary products (given its relative abundance of natural resources per worker). With the opening of mineral market opportunities in Japan, the mining sector began to flourish. Together with the rise in price of energy raw materials in the world market during the first and second oil crisis, the fuels and minerals sector began to catch up with, and finally overtook the primary products sector around mid-1980s (Promfret 1995). There is also an increasing share in non-primary products exports. We can see these changes, over the years, in figure 5 below.
Figure 5: Contribution to exports of goods and services by sector in Australia from 1950-51 to 1992-93
Source: Table 1.1 (Promfret 1995, pg. 33)
The import composition of Australia's trade has been considerably more stable than export composition, and that "manufactures dominate imports and primary products are of minor significance" (Promfret 1995, pg. 34). The composition of Australia's imports, over the years, is shown in figure 6 overleaf.
Figure 6: Composition of Australia's imports of goods and services, 1950-51 to 1992-93
Source: Table 1.2 (Promfret 1995, pg. 34)
According to the index of trade specialisation in Promfret (1995, pg. 35), reproduced here as figure 7 overleaf, the primary products exhibits a fluctuation around positive two-thirds (with no trend). For manufactures, this indicator has been highly negative but declining over the decades (less negative) suggesting that "Australia is becoming more involved in intra-industry trade in manufactures and gaining competitiveness in some niche markets" (Ibid, pg. 34). As for the service sector, the indicator is slightly negative, especially in more recent years. Promfret (1995) attributes this to the more rapid rise of service exports (notably tourism and education services) over imports.
MERCHANDISE TRADE
Australia's merchandise trade increased by 8% to A$168.2 billion in 1997, giving a trade surplus of A$1.3 billion, up from a deficit of A$1.4 billion the year before.
Figure 7: Index of trade specialisation, 1950-51 to 1990-91 (Current value of net exports / exports plus imports)
Source: Table 1.3 (Promfret 1995, pg. 35)
Figure 8 below show the merchandise trade in Australia from 1987 to 1997. Note that it was the first trade surplus since 1993.
N.A.
Figure 8: Australia's merchandise trade from 1987 to 1997 (in current price)
According to the Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade (1998a), merchandise exports were valued at A$84.8 billion in 1997, up 10% from 1996. In 1997, merchandise exports comprised 59% primary products, 10% Simply transformed manufactures (STMs), 23% Elaborately transformed manufactures (ETMs) and 8% other exports.
ETMs' share of total merchandise exports has increased from 19% in 1992 to 23% in 1997. Primary products' share has decreased from 62% to 59% over the same period. Manufactures exports have increased by 11% annually since 1992, largely due to strong growth in the export of ETMs. This increases the share of total merchandise exports from 28% to 33% in 1997. Figure 9 below illustrates the broad composition of exports in the above-mentioned four categories for 1992 and 1997.
N.A.
Figure 9: Broad composition of merchandise exports in 1992 and 1997
A better illustration with more specific commodity groups for the year 1960, 1980 and 1997, are shown in figure 10 and 11.
Figure 10: Exports of goods by commodity groups
Source: ABS catalogue no. 5368.0 (various issues)
Figure 11: Imports of goods by commodity groups
Source: ABS catalogue no. 5368.0 (various issues)
Merchandise imports increased by 6% to A$83.4 billion in 1997. It have always been dominated by ETMs. In 1997, merchandise imports comprised 13% primary products, 10% STMs, 76% ETMs and 1% other imports. These compositions has changed little from 1992 when imports were made up of 13% primary products, 11% STMs, 73% ETMs and 2% other imports as shown below:
N.A.
Figure 12: Broad composition of merchandise imports in 1992 and 1997
According to the Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade (1998a), nine out of Australia's top 10 export commodities in 1997 were primary products (with the exception of aluminium), while nine out of its top ten imports were ETMs (with the exception of crude petroleum).
TRADE IN SERVICES
Australia's trade in services has grown strongly since the opening of the economy to international competition in the early 1980s. According to the Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade (1998b), trade in services increased by 7% per annum in real term between 1985-86 and 1995-96 (when it totalled A$39.4 billion).
In 1985-86, services trade accounted for 20% of total trade in goods and services, and had increased to 23% by 1995-96 (ibid). In 1995-96, Australia's trade in services was in credit by A$93 million, recovering from a deficit of A$3.8 billion in 1985-86. (see figure 13 below)
N.A.
Figure 13: Services trade from 1985-86 to 1995-96 (in current prices)
In real terms, exports of services have grown by an average of about 9% annually since 1985-86 (by 10% to A$ 22.5 billion in 1995-96), while imports of services have increased by 5% per annum over the same period (by 3% to A$22.4 billion in 1995-96).
Looking at the broad composition of Australia's international trade in goods and services again (this time in 1989-90 dollar terms), exports of manufactures have increased by 13% annually since 1985-86, while exports of services increased by 8% per annum.
N.A.
Figure 14: Exports and Imports by broad sector (in 1989-90 dollar terms)
In real terms, imports of services comprised 20% of total imports in 1995-96. This has decreased from 23% in 1985-86, reflecting the slower growth of the import of services relative to merchandise imports.
The Australia's composition of exports and imports of services in 1995-96 is shown in figure 15 overleaf. The exports comprised 7% shipment, 26% other transportation services, 46% travel, and 20% other services, while imports of services were more evenly distributed between the four types. Their exports and imports trend (by type) from the period 1985-86 to 1995-96 is shown in figure 16 overleaf, which also indicate the balance of trade of each service type.
N.A.
Figure 15: Exports and Imports of services by type (share of total) for the year1995-96
N.A.
Figure 16: Trend of Exports and Imports of services (by type) from the period 1985-86 to 1995-96
N.A.
Figure 16 (cont..)
Inter-industry or intra-industry trade?
Inter-industry trade occurs when a country exports and imports different product categories; and when a country is both exporting and importing items in the same product classification categories, the country is engaging in intra-industry trade (Appleyard & Field 1998).
The measurement of the degree of intra-industry trade for a country can be determined by the formula in Appleyard & Field (1998, pg. 199):
With the merchandise trade figures (ie. excluding services trade) from Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade (1998a) using ABS data (in appendix 1), we can compute Australia's index of intra-industry trade using the above formula. As shown in appendix 3, the index for 1997 worked out to be 0.47, up from 0.44 in 1992. This means that Australia has a moderate amount of intra-industry trade.
Based on figures illustrated, we can conclude that Australia's pattern of trade fits with that predicted by the H-O theory where we observe Australia exporting more than 50% of its total merchandise exports in primary products, and importing more than 70% of its total merchandise imports in ETMs.
However, the share of total exports held by the primary products is experiencing a declining trend (from its traditionally high portion), while the share of manufactures and services trade in total exports had been expanding over the last few decades. This suggests that Australia have been successful in promoting and developing new manufacturing and service industries by influencing its factor of endowment (thus comparative advantage) through investment in training, education, R & D activities and other government policies that promote areas where they exhibit high productivity.
We have also concluded that Australia has a moderate amount of intra-industry trade. In view of this, a better trade theory that could help explain this phenomenon could be the Linder theory where it cited product differentiation to be a reason.
Number of Words: 2098
Appleyard, D.R. and Field, A.J. (1998) International Economics, 3rd ed., Irwin, Boston
Bloch, Harry (1998) 'Economics (International) 311' lecture notes, accessed on 1 Sep 1998 at [http://www.cbs.curtin.edu.au/units/ef/ei311/98lect3.doc]
Clark, David (1997) Student Economic Briefs 1998, John Fairfax Publications, Melbourne
Department of Foreign Affairs & Trade (1998a) Composition of Trade, Statistical services & publications, Barton, ACT
Department of Foreign Affairs & Trade (1998b) Trade in Services, Australia, Statistical services & publications, Barton, ACT
King, Stephen and Lloyd, Peter, editor (1993) Economic Rationalism - Dead end or way forward?, Allen & Unwin Pty Ltd, NSW
Leamer, E.E. (1987) 'Paths of development in the three-factor, n-good general equilibrium model', Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 95, No. 5, pg. 961-99
Lewis, P., Garnett, A., Drake, P., Juttner, J., Norris, K. and Treadgold, M. (1998) Issues, Indicators and Ideas: a guide to the Australian economy, 2nd ed.,
Addison Wesley Longman Australia, South Melbourne
Promfret, Richard, editor (1995) Australia's Trade Policies, Oxford University Press, South Melbourne
Salvatore, D., (1995) International Economics, 5th ed., McGraw-Hill, New York
World Bank (1993) World Tables 1992-93, John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore
Appendix 1: Australia's merchandise trade by broad category in A$ (Table 1)*
Appendix 2: Australia's merchandise trade by broad category in % share (Table 2)*
Appendix 3: Measurement of Australia's Intra-industry trade index for 1992 and 1997
* Extracted from the Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade (1998a).
Return to Assignments for Semester 2, 1998